The large income benefits of migration

This is an English summary of my master’s thesis in policy economics (University of Leuven). The thesis can be downloaded here.

Injustice, inefficiency and harm of migration restrictions

Unequal pay for equal work, a welfare loss of billions of euros, and thousands of deaths. Injustice, inefficiency and harm are the three consequences of a migration restriction or closed borders policy.

Migration restrictions create a global wage gap, with real wages (for the same work, the same skills and the same employer education level) about 4 times higher in rich countries than in low and middle income countries (Clemens, Montenegro & Pritchett, 2008). This factor 4 is the place premium that measures the increase in income of a foreign worker from a poor country who is going to work in a rich country. This place premium in wages is one of the biggest price disruptions on the international market. The hourly wage in a poor region is 75% lower than in a rich region. This percentage can be compared with the gender pay gap: in Belgium the average hourly wage of a woman is about 8% lower than a man (Van Hove & De Vos, 2017). The pay gap based on origin is almost 10 times larger than the pay gap based on gender.

This injustice is the result of a global labor market that is not in equilibrium. Productive workers are prevented from going to work where labor productivity is highest (Borjas, 2015). In poorer countries there is a labor surplus (or capital shortage), in richer countries there is a labor shortage (or capital surplus).

This disequilibrium in the global labor market also leads to a loss of productivity worth billions of euros. If workers cannot migrate to places with the highest labor productivity and entrepreneurs cannot migrate to places with the best entrepreneurial climate, then win-win situations are hampered. Stopping migrant families at the border prevents mutually beneficial transactions between employees and employers, between producers and consumers, between buyers and sellers, between tenants and landlords. Just like freer international movement of goods and capital, freer movement of workers will improve the efficiency of the world economy. A freer migration can increase real global income (according to purchasing power) or gross world product (GWP) by 10% to 100% (Clemens, 2011). For comparison: the potential global income growth of freer migration is an order of magnitude higher than the income growth from further liberalizing international goods and capital markets. The removal of barriers to goods and capital flows can increase global income by only a few percent (Clemens, 2011).

Finally, limiting migration and closing national borders is directly harmful. There is direct damage because migrants, asylum seekers and refugees often take unnecessarily high risks of entering a country. At least 1000 people die every year in their attempt to reach Europe via the Mediterranean (UNITED, 2018).

The income changes of migration

The income effects for different population groups were studied on the basis of a literature review (see references). The literature studies show coherent results. The migration surplus per migrant measures the expected increase of the world income (the sum of everyone’s income) when one extra migrant from a poor region is admitted to the labor market of a rich region. This migration surplus is almost 30,000 euros per year per migrant.

The migrants are the biggest winners, because they can see their real wage multiplied by a factor of 4.  But the native population in the recipient countries can also benefit from immigration. Extra migrants means: extra customers and extra tenants, but also extra entrepreneurs and of course extra workers who can, for example, mitigate the public finance problems associated with an aging population in rich countries. All this contributes to the local economy in a recipient country. As a result, about one third of the migration surplus of € 30,000 per year per migrant, is to the benefit of the native population, in particular capital owners (employers, shareholders, real estate owners).

The average real wages of native workers are almost unaffected by immigration: studies indicate small income changes, sometimes a bit positive, sometimes a bit negative. If mainly low-skilled workers immigrate, then the wages of native low-skilled workers and the already present migrants may fall. For the low-skilled workers in the rich region, this is a decrease of around 1000 euros per year per new migrant. This cost is distributed over the entire population of low-skilled native workers and can be more than offset by the increase of 10,000 euros per year for the rest of the native population. With a progressive tax and income redistribution, the net wages of (low-skilled) native workers can rise.

The migrants receive roughly two thirds of the migration surplus (i.e. € 20,000 per year per migrant), but a bit less than half of their share is send to their relatives who are left behind in the poor region. Due to these remittances, the population in the countries of origin can also benefit from emigration. Especially workers in those poor countries can see an income increase.

The result of the literature overview can be summarized in the figure below. The width and height of the bars correspond to the population size and the real incomes of the various population groups, respectively. The dotted lines represent the situation after migration. The biggest winners are the migrants (green bar) who see their income increase sharply. The remaining workers in the countries of origin (yellow bar) see their income rise because there is less labor surplus in those countries during emigration and because the local population receives money transfers (remittances) from the migrants. The capital owners in the recipient countries (blue bar) see their capital income increase because their capital becomes more productive with extra workers. The average wages of workers (red bars) remain approximately constant. The highly educated can get slightly higher incomes, the lower educated slightly lower.

Income effects of migration

Explanations of the income effects

On the basis of a global general equilibrium model, explanations were given for the absence of significant decreases in the average wages of native workers due to immigration. The two most important explanations for this wage inelasticity of native workers are:
1) the complementarity of migrant and native labor in the short run, because immigrants are more mobile and can therefore ‘grease the wheels of labor market’ in the rich region by migrating to places where their productivity is highest (Borjas, 2001), and
2) the additional capital investments in the long run , because they can greatly increase productivity and employment in the rich region.

Policy implications

Economics professor Bryan Caplan and supporters of open borders (Caplan, 2015; Matthews, 2014; Open Borders, 2019) argue that migration restrictions are comparable to stopping job applicants and workers at the gates of companies, or stopping customers at the doors of shops. This restriction of freedom is not only harmful to the applicant, worker or customer, but also to the employer and shopkeeper.

There is a lot of arbitrariness in the policy of closed borders: why should borders be closed to migrant workers while they are open to flows of capital and goods and to tourists? Why should borders be closed between countries or country unions (such as the EU), while they are open between municipalities, provinces, regions and states?

Migration restrictions lead to an unjust pay gap between poor and rich regions, a global loss of wealth of billions of euros (almost half of total income), an aggravation of the aging problem in rich countries, a disadvantage for both native people and migrants, a huge death toll of migrants, a restriction on freedom of consumers and producers, and an undesirable arbitrariness. If we look at the economic literature on migration, we see a clear consensus among economists that a policy of freer migration offers more advantages than disadvantages (New American Economy, 2017; Open Borders, 2019c).

Opening up national borders for labor migration (Caplan, 2015; Matthews, 2014; Open Borders, 2019a) is the most far reaching but logical recommendation of this study. Open borders between countries are an extension of open borders between municipalities: just as one can move from one municipality to another (subject to registration in the new municipality), one could move from one country to another for living, working and shopping. In the short run, when completely opening borders is not politically feasible, one could gradually liberalize migration and increase the immigration rate.

References

Peer reviewed academic articles

Aleksynska, M., & Tritah, A. (2015). The heterogeneity of immigrants, host countries’ income and productivity: a channel accounting approach. Economic Inquiry, 53(1), 150-172.

Alesina, A., Harnoss, J., & Rapoport, H. (2016). Birthplace diversity and economic prosperity. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(2), 101-138.

Angrist, J. D., & Kugler, A. D. (2003). Protective or counter‐productive? Labour market institutions and the effect of immigration on EU natives. The Economic Journal, 113(488), F302-F331.

Aubry, A., Burzyński, M., & Docquier, F. (2016). The welfare impact of global migration in OECD countries. Journal of International Economics, 101, 1-21.

Aydemir, A., & Borjas, G. J. (2007). Cross-country variation in the impact of international migration: Canada, Mexico, and the United States. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(4), 663-708.

Bargain, O., Orsini, K. & Peichi, A. (2011). Labor Supply Elasticities in Europe and the US. IZA Discussion Paper No. 5820.

Bauer, T. & Zimmermann, K. (1999). Assessment of Possible Migration Pressure and its Labour Market Impact Following EU Enlargement to Central and Eastern Europe. IZA Research Report No. 3.

Blau, F. D., & Kahn, L. M. (2015). Immigration and the Distribution of Incomes. In Handbook of the economics of international migration (Vol. 1, pp. 793-843). North-Holland.

Borjas, G. J., & Ramey, V. A. (1995). Foreign competition, market power, and wage inequality. The quarterly journal of economics, 110(4), 1075-1110.

Borjas, G. J., Freeman, R. B., Katz, L. F., DiNardo, J., & Abowd, J. M. (1997). How much do immigration and trade affect labor market outcomes?. Brookings papers on economic activity, 1997(1), 1-90.

Borjas, G.J. (1995). The Economic Benefits of Immigration. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(2), 3-22.

Borjas, G. J. (2001). Does immigration grease the wheels of the labor market?. Brookings papers on economic activity, 2001(1), 69-119.

Borjas, G. J. (2003). The Labor Demand Curve is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1335-1374.

Borjas, G. J. (2006). Native internal migration and the labor market impact of immigration. Journal of Human resources, 41(2), 221-258.

Borjas, G. J. (2008). Labor outflows and labor inflows in Puerto Rico. Journal of Human Capital, 2(1), 32-68.

Borjas, G. J. (2013). The analytics of the wage effect of immigration. IZA Journal of Migration, 2(1), 22.

Borjas, G. J. (2015). Immigration and globalization: A review essay. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4), 961-74.

Bratsberg, B., Raaum, O., Røed, M., & Schøne, P. (2010). Immigration Wage Impacts by Origin (No. 1030). Centre for Research and Analysis of Migration (CReAM), Department of Economics, University College London.

Card, D. (2001). Immigrant inflows, native outflows, and the local labor market impacts of higher immigration. Journal of Labor Economics, 19(1), 22-64.

Card, D. (2009). Immigration and inequality. American Economic Review, 99(2), 1-21.

Clemens, M. (2011). Economics and Emigration: Trillion-Dollar Bills on the Sidewalk? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 83–106.

Clemens, M. A. (2013). Why do programmers earn more in Houston than Hyderabad? Evidence from randomized processing of US visas. American Economic Review, 103(3), 198-202.

Cortes, P. (2008). The effect of low-skilled immigration on US prices: evidence from CPI data. Journal of political Economy, 116(3), 381-422.

D’Amuri, F., & Peri, G. (2014). Immigration, jobs, and employment protection: evidence from Europe before and during the great recession. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(2), 432-464.

Di Giovanni, J., Levchenko, A. A., & Ortega, F. (2015). A global view of cross-border migration. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13(1), 168-202.

Docquier, F., Özden, Ç., & Peri, G. (2011). The wage effects of immigration and emigration. The World Bank.

Docquier, F., Ozden, Ç., & Peri, G. (2013). The labour market effects of immigration and emigration in OECD countries. The Economic Journal, 124(579), 1106-1145.

Docquier, F., Machado, J., and Sekkat, K. (2015). Efficiency Gains from Liberalizing Labor Mobility. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 00(0), 1–44.

Dustmann, C., Frattini, T., & Preston, I. P. (2012). The effect of immigration along the distribution of wages. Review of Economic Studies, 80(1), 145-173.

Dustmann, C., Frattini, T., & Glitz, A. (2007). The impact of migration: a review of the economic evidence. Centre for Research and Analysis of Migration (CReAM), Department of Economics, University College London, and EPolicy LTD, November, 1-113.

Edo, A. (2018). The impact of immigration on the labor market. Journal of Economic Surveys. doi:10.1111/joes.12300.

Elsner, B. (2013). Emigration and wages: The EU enlargement experiment. Journal of International Economics, 91(1), 154-163.

Felbermayr, G. J., Hiller, S., & Sala, D. (2010). Does immigration boost per capita income?. Economics Letters, 107(2), 177-179.

Foged, M., & Peri, G. (2016). Immigrants’ effect on native workers: New analysis on longitudinal data. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 8(2), 1-34.

Friedberg, R. M., & Hunt, J. (1995). The impact of immigrants on host country wages, employment and growth. Journal of Economic perspectives, 9(2), 23-44.

Gagnon, J. (2011). Stay With US? The Impact of Emigration on Wages in Honduras, OECD Development Centre Working Paper No. 300.

Gibson, J., McKenzie, D., Rohorua, H., & Stillman, S. (2017). The long-term impacts of international migration: Evidence from a lottery. The World Bank Economic Review, 32(1), 127-147.

Glitz, A. (2012). The labor market impact of immigration: A quasi-experiment exploiting immigrant location rules in Germany. Journal of Labor Economics, 30(1), 175-213.

González, L., & Ortega, F. (2008). How do very open economies absorb large immigration flows. Recent Evidence from Spanish Regions. Economic Reports, 06-08.

Hall, R., Jones, C.I. (1999). Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much Output per Worker Than Others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116.

Hamilton, B. and Whalley, J. (1984). Efficiency and Distributional Implications of Global Restrictions on Labour Mobility. Journal of Development Economics, 14, 61–75.

Hanson, G. H. (2005). Emigration, labor supply, and earnings in Mexico (No. w11412). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Hanson, G. H. (2009). The Economic Consequences of the International Migration of Labor. Annual Review of Economics, 1(1), 179–207.

Hendricks, L., & Schoellman, T. (2017). Human capital and development accounting: New evidence from wage gains at migration. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(2), 665-700.

Iranzo, S., & Peri, G. (2009). Migration and trade: Theory with an application to the Eastern–Western European integration. Journal of International Economics, 79(1), 1-19.

Iregui, A. M. (2005). Efficiency Gains from the Elimination of Global Restrictions on Labour Mobility. In G. J. Borjas and J. Crisp (eds.), Poverty, International Migration and Asylum, Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp. 211-238.

Jaeger, D. A. (1996). Skill Differences and the Effect of Immigrants on the Wages of Natives. US Bureau of Labor Statistics Working Paper, 273. Revised in 2007.

Jaumotte, M. F., Koloskova, K., & Saxena, M. S. C. (2016). Impact of migration on income levels in advanced economies. International Monetary Fund.

Kennan, J. (2013). Open Borders. Review of Economic Dynamics, 16, L1–L13.

Klein, P. and Ventura, G. (2007). TFP Differences and the Aggregate Effects of Labor Mobility in the Long Run, B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 7, article 10.

Klein, P. and Ventura, G. (2009). Productivity Differences and the Dynamic Effects of Labor Movements. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, 1059–1073.

Leeson, G. (2012). Migration as a policy response to population ageing. International Risk Governance Council – Public Sector Governance of Emerging Risks.

León‐Ledesma, M. & Piracha, M. (2004). International Migration and the Role of Remittances in Eastern Europe. International Migration, 42, 65-83.

Lewis, E. G. (2011). Immigrant-native substitutability: The role of language ability (No. w17609). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Longhi, S., Nijkamp, P., & Poot, J. (2005). A meta‐analytic assessment of the effect of immigration on wages. Journal of economic surveys, 19(3), 451-477.

Manacorda, M., Manning, A., & Wadsworth, J. (2012). The impact of immigration on the structure of wages: theory and evidence from Britain. Journal of the European economic association, 10(1), 120-151.

Mishra, P. (2007a). Emigration and Wages in Source Countries: Evidence from Mexico, Journal of Development Economics, 82, 180-199.

Mishra, P. (2007b). Emigration and Brain-Drain: Evidence from the Caribbean, The B.E. Journals in Economic Analysis & Policy, 7(1) Article 24.

Mishra, P. (2014). Emigration and wages in source countries: A survey of the empirical literature. International Handbook on Migration and Economic Development, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 241-266.

Monras, J. (2018). Immigration and wage dynamics: Evidence from the mexican peso crisis.

Moses, J. W. & Letnes, B. (2004a). The Economic Costs to International Labor Restrictions: Revisiting the Empirical Discussion. World Development, 32(10), 1609–1626.

Münz, R., Straubhaar, T., Vadean, F., & Vadean, N. (2006). The costs and benefits of European immigration. HWWI Policy Reports 3, Hamburg Institute of International Economics (HWWI).

Okkerse, L. (2008). How to measure labour market effects of immigration: A review. Journal of Economic Surveys, 22(1), 1-30.

Orrenius, P. M., & Zavodny, M. (2007). Does immigration affect wages? A look at occupation-level evidence. Labour Economics, 14(5), 757-773.

Ortega, F. & Peri, G. (2013). Migration, Trade & Income, IZA Discussion Paper 7325.

Ottaviano, G. I., & Peri, G. (2008). Immigration and national wages: Clarifying the theory and the empirics (No. w14188). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Ottaviano, G. I., & Peri, G. (2012). Rethinking the effect of immigration on wages. Journal of the European economic association, 10(1), 152-197.

Ratha, D., De, S., Ju Kim, E., Plaza, S., Schuettler, K., Seshan, G. & Yameogo, N.D. (2018), Migration and Remittances, Recent Developments and Outlook. Migration and Development Brief 29. World Bank Group.

Walmsley, T. L. & Winters, L. A. (2005). Relaxing the Restrictions on the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons: A Simulation Analysis. Journal of Economic Integration, 20, 688–726.

Books

Altonji, J. G., & Card, D. (1991). The effects of immigration on the labor market outcomes of less-skilled natives. In Immigration, trade, and the labor market (pp. 201-234). University of Chicago Press.

Bouton, L., Paul, S., & Tiongson, E. R. (2011). The impact of emigration on source country wages: evidence from the Republic of Moldova. The World Bank.

Clemens, M. A., Montenegro, C. E., & Pritchett, L. (2008). The place premium: wage differences for identical workers across the US border. The World Bank.

Iregui, A. M. (2005). Efficiency Gains from the Elimination of Global Restrictions on Labour Mobility. In G. J. Borjas and J. Crisp (eds.), Poverty, International Migration and Asylum, Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp. 211-238.

Moses, J. W., & Letnes, B. (2004b). If people were money: Estimating the gain and scope of free migration. In G. J. Borjas & J. Crisp (Eds.), Poverty, international migration and asylum. London: Palgrave, pp. 188-210.

National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine. (2017). The economic and fiscal consequences of immigration. National Academies Press.

Posner, E. & Weyl, G. (2018). Radical Markets. Uprooting Capitalism and Democracy for a Just Society. Princeton University Press. www.radicalmarkets.com.

Pritchett, L. (2006). Let Their People Come: Breaking the Gridlock on Global Labor Mobility. Center for Global Development, Washington DC.

Van Hove, H. & De Vos, D. (2017). De loonkloof tussen vrouwen en mannen in België. Instituut voor de gelijkheid van vrouwen en mannen, Brussel.

World Bank (2005) Global Economic Prospects 2006: Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration, Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

World Bank (2018). Moving for Prosperity. Global Migration and Labor Markets. World Bank Group, Policy Research Report, Washington.

Internet and media

Bulman, M. (2017). Brexit: People voted to leave EU because they feared immigration, major survey finds. Independent, 28-06-2017.

Caplan, B. (2015). The case for open borders, Time, 7-10-2015 time.com/4062074/migrants-open-borders/

Matthews, D. (2014). The case for open borders, Vox, 15-12-2014 www.vox.com/2014/9/13/6135905/open-borders-bryan-caplan-interview-gdp-double/

New American Economy (2017). An Open Letter from 1,470 Economists on Immigration. www.newamericaneconomy.org/feature/an-open-letter-from-1470-economists-on-immigration/

Open Borders (2019a). openborders.info/

Open Borders (2019b). openborders.info/immigration-tariffs/

Open Borders (2019c). openborders.info/economist-consensus/

Peri, G. (2013). The economic benefits of immigration, Berkeley Review of Latin American Studies, University of California, Berkeley clas.berkeley.edu/research/immigration-economic-benefits-immigration

UNITED (2018). The Fatal Policies of Fortress Europe, list of deaths. http://www.unitedagainstracism.org/campaigns/refugee-campaign/fortress-europe/

Dit bericht werd geplaatst in Artikels, Blog, English texts en getagged met , , , , . Maak dit favoriet permalink.

Plaats een reactie